chessgames.com
Members · Prefs · Collections · Openings · Endgames · Sacrifices · History · Search Kibitzing · Kibitzer's Café · Chessforums · Tournament Index · Players · Kibitzing

Louis Stumpers
L Stumpers 
 
Number of games in database: 55
Years covered: 1932 to 1969
Overall record: +13 -32 =10 (32.7%)*
   * Overall winning percentage = (wins+draws/2) / total games.

Repertoire Explorer
Most played openings
D94 Grunfeld (3 games)
E60 King's Indian Defense (2 games)
B59 Sicilian, Boleslavsky Variation, 7.Nb3 (2 games)
C65 Ruy Lopez, Berlin Defense (2 games)
D45 Queen's Gambit Declined Semi-Slav (2 games)

Search Sacrifice Explorer for Louis Stumpers
Search Google for Louis Stumpers


LOUIS STUMPERS
(born Aug-30-1911, died Sep-27-2003, 92 years old) Netherlands

[what is this?]

Frans Louis Henri Marie Stumpers was born in Eindhoven, Netherlands, on 30 August 1911. (1) He was champion of the Eindhoven Chess Club in 1938, 1939, 1946, 1947, 1948, 1949, 1951, 1952, 1953, 1955, 1957, 1958, 1961 and 1963, (2) and champion of the North Brabant Chess Federation (Noord Brabantse Schaak Bond, NBSB) in 1934, 1935, 1936, 1937, 1938, 1939, 1940, 1941, 1942, 1943, 1944, 1946, 1948, 1949, 1950, 1951, 1952, 1953, 1954, 1955, 1959, 1961, 1962, 1963, 1964, 1965, 1966 and 1967. (3) He participated in five Dutch Chess Championships, with a 4th place in 1948, (4) and represented his country at the 1st European Team Championship, in Vienna in 1957 (two games, vs Josef Platt and Max Dorn). (5) From 1945 and until about 1956, he was first Secretary and then Chairman of the NBSB. (3)

Stumpers was a physicist, and worked for the Philips company as an assistant from 1928. During 1934-1937, he studied at the University of Utrecht, where he took the master's degree. (6) In 1938 he was again employed at Philips, (6) and at a tournament in 1942, he supplied the hungry chess players with food from his employer. (3) After the war, he made a career in physics, with patents and awards on information ('radio') technology. He received degrees from several universities and colleges, including in Poland and Japan. (1, 3, 6) He retired from Philips in 1972, but continued teaching, (6) partly as professor at the University of Utrecht (1977-1981). (7) He was also Vice President (1975-1981) and Honorary President (1990-2003) of URSI, the International Union of Radio Science. (8)

Louis Stumpers married Mieke Driessen in 1954. They had five children, three girls and two boys. (6)

1) Online Familieberichten 1.0 (2016), http://www.online-familieberichten.... Digitaal Tijdschrift, 5 (255), http://www.geneaservice.nl/ar/2003/....
2) Eindhovense Schaakvereniging (2016), http://www.eindhovenseschaakverenig....
3) Noord Brabantse Schaak Bond (2016), http://www.nbsb.nl/pkalgemeen/pk-er... Their main page: http://www.nbsb.nl.
4) Schaaksite.nl (2016), http://www.schaaksite.nl/2016/01/01....
5) Olimpbase, http://www.olimpbase.org/1957eq/195....
6) K. Teer, Levensbericht F. L. H. M. Stumpers, in: Levensberichten en herdenkingen, 2004, Amsterdam, pp. 90-97, http://www.dwc.knaw.nl/DL/levensber.... Also available at http://www.hagenbeuk.nl/wp-content/....
7) Catalogus Professorum Academię Rheno-Traiectinę, https://profs.library.uu.nl/index.p....
8) URSI websites (2016), http://www.ursi.org/en/ursi_structu... and http://www.ursi.org/en/ursi_structu....

Suggested reading: Eindhovense Schaakvereniging 100 jaar 1915-2015, by Jules Welling. Stumpers' doctoral thesis Eenige onderzoekingen over trillingen met frequentiemodulatie (Studies on Vibration with Frequency Modulation) is found at http://repository.tudelft.nl/island...

Last updated: 2017-06-26 02:43:54

 page 1 of 3; games 1-25 of 55  PGN Download
Game  ResultMoves YearEvent/LocaleOpening
1. L Stumpers vs J Lehr  1-0191932EindhovenD18 Queen's Gambit Declined Slav, Dutch
2. Prins vs L Stumpers  1-0391936NED-ch prelimB20 Sicilian
3. L Stumpers vs E Spanjaard  1-0551938Dutch Ch prelimE02 Catalan, Open, 5.Qa4
4. E Sapira vs L Stumpers 0-1251938NBSB - FlandersD94 Grunfeld
5. A J Wijnans vs L Stumpers  1-0361939NED-chB05 Alekhine's Defense, Modern
6. J van den Bosch vs L Stumpers  ½-½581939NED-ch11A48 King's Indian
7. L Stumpers vs S Landau 0-1411939NED-ch11D33 Queen's Gambit Declined, Tarrasch
8. H van Steenis vs L Stumpers  1-0251939NED-chB02 Alekhine's Defense
9. L Stumpers vs H Kramer  0-1361940HilversumE25 Nimzo-Indian, Samisch
10. A J van den Hoek vs L Stumpers  1-0271941BondswedstrijdenB10 Caro-Kann
11. T van Scheltinga vs L Stumpers 1-0351942NED-ch12D94 Grunfeld
12. W Wolthuis vs L Stumpers  ½-½521946NED-ch prelim IC58 Two Knights
13. L Stumpers vs J H Marwitz  1-0401946NED-ch prelim ID31 Queen's Gambit Declined
14. G Fontein vs L Stumpers  ½-½261946NED-ch prelim ID94 Grunfeld
15. L Stumpers vs H van Steenis 0-1241946NED-ch prelim ID28 Queen's Gambit Accepted, Classical
16. C B van den Berg vs L Stumpers  1-0581946NED-ch prelim ID19 Queen's Gambit Declined Slav, Dutch
17. L Stumpers vs Euwe 0-1301946NED-ch prelim IE60 King's Indian Defense
18. L Stumpers vs Cortlever  ½-½501946NED-ch prelim IE60 King's Indian Defense
19. L Stumpers vs Grob 1-0601947Int BA55 Old Indian, Main line
20. L Stumpers vs H van Steenis  0-1331947Int BD23 Queen's Gambit Accepted
21. Tartakower vs L Stumpers 1-0241947Int BD74 Neo-Grunfeld, 6.cd Nxd5, 7.O-O
22. V Soultanbeieff vs L Stumpers  ½-½461947Int BD96 Grunfeld, Russian Variation
23. L Stumpers vs T van Scheltinga  1-0471948NED-ch14C97 Ruy Lopez, Closed, Chigorin
24. Prins vs L Stumpers  ½-½301948NED-chD02 Queen's Pawn Game
25. J G Baay vs L Stumpers  1-0401948NED-ch14E37 Nimzo-Indian, Classical
 page 1 of 3; games 1-25 of 55  PGN Download
  REFINE SEARCH:   White wins (1-0) | Black wins (0-1) | Draws (1/2-1/2) | Stumpers wins | Stumpers loses  
 

Kibitzer's Corner
< Earlier Kibitzing  · PAGE 291 OF 291 ·  Later Kibitzing>
May-24-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  perfidious: <WannaBe: Computer defeats human in game 1 in 5 game match of Go....>

Rut roh.

May-25-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  WannaBe: I made a mistake in my previous post, it was the best of 3 games, not 5. And computer have clinched it.

http://money.cnn.com/2017/05/25/tec...

Time to run for the hills, Skynet's right around the corner... Where are you Sarah Connor?

We are doomed, doooooooooooom'd!!

Jun-15-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  WannaBe: Well, that is great, but can it speak Jive like Barbara Billingsley?

https://www.theatlantic.com/technol...

Jun-15-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  Sneaky: I've been thinking about a kind of abstract two-player symmetrical game of the simplest type.

Forgive me if this is dreadfully dull—I honestly am trying to figure out whether or not it's so trivial of a game that it can be dismissed ... or perhaps it's one of those games like rock-scissors-paper which are effectively random but can employ psychology if somehow you can "get in your opponent's head." If there is some interest to it, I imagine it could be the core mechanic behind a more elaborate table or computer game.

<SETUP> There are 6 jars, 3 for each player. They are labeled "A, B, C" for each player. The jars are opaque: one player has black jars, the other player has white jars.

Each player also receives 10 marbles; the white player's marbles are white; the black player's marbles are black.

Each player puts a $20 bill in each jar, and an extra $5 in jar C. (This is why I call jar C the "premium jar" ... it's a better to win that one than any other.)

<PLAY> In secret, each player puts any number of their marbles in each of the three jars. You are allowed to put no marbles in a jar, all your marbles in a jar, any distribution you can think of. For example, one player might try in 3 in A, 3 in B, and 4 in C.

<OUTCOME> The jars containing cash and marbles are now opened up and the marbles counted. For each pair of jars (A, B, and C) the player who had the most marbles in their jar takes all of the money from both jars.

<EXAMPLES> I decide to forgo the $25 prize and make my distribution (5,5,0). My opponent tries the (3,3,4) distribution described above. Ergo, I win $40 from the first two jars, lost $25 from C, and profit $15.

Suppose we play again. I stick with my original plan with (5,5,0). My opponent, now wise to my tricks, plays (3,6,1). The jars are compared and he has won both jars B and C, winning $45.

For round three I try to make a play for the premium jar C: I play (5,0,5). My opponent sticks to his (3,6,1) strategy. Now I win jars A and C for $45.

<ANALYSIS> I imagine a computer program that selects the distribution entirely at random. I am confident that if I played (3,3,4) against it every time, I would come out ahead, simply because my setup is "smarter" in that it makes a stronger play for the premium jar. Therefore there must some strategies better than pure random picks, which means there must be a best strategy. But what is it?

Jun-15-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  WannaBe: So, if two jars have the same amount of marble(s), it would be a push and no money exchange hands(?)

I think a computer program, that brute force all the possibilities will be the way to go.

W's strategy (0,0,10) and you compare that to B's strategy (0,1,9); (0,2,8); (0,3,7);.....(10,0,0)

Then you move on to the next possible W's marble distribution (0,1,9), etc...

Jun-15-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  Sneaky: <So, if two jars have the same amount of marble(s), it would be a push and no money exchange hands(?)> Exactly. Draws are possible for either a pair of jars or even all three.
Jun-18-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  al wazir: <Sneaky>:

1. Clearly any useful strategy would have to involve some randomness, since a non-random strategy is predictable and hence beatable.

2. Suppose there is an optimal strategy, a strategy that guarantees that its adherent always wins over an extended series of plays.

3. If both black and white play the *same* optimal strategy, neither would come out ahead.

4. This contradicts assumption 2.

5. Therefore there is no winning strategy.

6. The best that can be achieved is a strategy which ensures that its adherent doesn't lose.

7. It is not obvious that such a strategy exists. I can imagine that there are three strategies: call them X, Y, and Z. X always beats Y, Y always beats Z, and Z always beats X, and X, Y, and Z win against all other strategies.

8. Over an extended series of plays it would become apparent which strategy one's opponent is playing. Thus, if my opponent's strategy is X, I would play Z, and then I would come out ahead.

9. Unless he changed to Y.

10. But then the pattern of his play would again become apparent, and I would shift to X.

11. Since he can just as readily discern what strategy *I* am following, and we have no grounds to assume that his understanding of the game is inferior to mine, he is as likely to play the strategy that defeats mine as vice versa. I might adopt a meta-strategy in which I sometimes follow X, sometimes Y, and sometimes Z. I'm afraid this gets me into metalogic and ties me into mental knots.

12. But I think it contradicts assumption 7.

13. The nontrivial question is, does there exist a strategy W that wins against anyone who doesn't follow the same strategy? And if so, is it unique?

14. There might be two or more different strategies, W, V, U, ..., each of which defeats any other strategy, but which draw against one another.

Jun-19-17  john barleycorn: Let A and B be the $20 jars and C the $25 jar. The worst strategy is to put all your marbles in one jar. Your opponent plays A=B=1 and C=8 to win a fortune. Splitting your 10 marbles among 2 jars and leave the 3 jar empty is also not the best idea in the world. If you would choose randomly one of the 27 possiblities to do so and the second player puts 1 marble into A, 3 into B, and 6 into C he will win provided the game is played often enough.

So, an optimum strategy has to consider at least one marble in each jar, the fact that your jar wins if it contains 1 marble more than the opponents corresponding jar and holding 2 more more marbles than your opponent's jar means nothing.

Furthermore, you cannot win/lose on all three jars, you cannot have 2 wins /losses and a draw, nor 2 draws and a win/loss.

Probably best is choosing randomly from the following (A;B;C)= (1;4;5), or any permutation thereof. Since your opponent may know that too, he may choose accordingly an thus making it an equal game.

Jun-19-17  john barleycorn: <sneaky> <if I played (3,3,4)>

consider:

(3,3,4) against (1,4,5), (1,5,4), (4,1,5), (4,5,1), (5,1,4), (5,4,1).

It is losing big time :-)

Jun-19-17  john barleycorn: <al wazir: <Sneaky>:

...

2. Suppose there is an optimal strategy, a strategy that guarantees that its adherent always wins over an extended series of plays.

3. If both black and white play the *same* optimal strategy, neither would come out ahead.

4. This contradicts assumption 2. >

How can you assume an always winning strategy which when copied by the opponent is not winning? All you can claim is a non-losing strategy in that case. There is a difference.

Jun-19-17  john barleycorn: <5. Therefore there is no winning strategy.

6. The best that can be achieved is a strategy which ensures that its adherent doesn't lose.

7. It is not obvious that such a strategy exists. ...>

ok, are you saying there is no winning strategy (your point 1. - 4.) and the existence of a "no-lose" strategy is questionable?

What the heck are you talking about?

Can you give an example where the relation "x is a better strategy than y" is not transitive?

Jun-19-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  johnlspouge: Rock-paper-scissors on a comparison of pure strategies: always "rock", always "paper", always "scissors".

[ https://arxiv.org/pdf/1406.2212.pdf ]

Non-transitivity holds for many patterns when matching patterns in a coin toss (the application I am most familiar with), as the reference mentions.

Define "better"?

Jun-19-17  john barleycorn: <johnlspouge: Rock-paper-scissors on a comparison of pure strategies: always "rock", always "paper", always "scissors".

[ https://arxiv.org/pdf/1406.2212.pdf ]

Non-transitivity holds for many patterns ...>

Wait,a non-transitive game is a different thing from a non-transitive strategy to play the game. In a non-transitive game it is a good strategy not to be the first to choose and play. and if it is not good to be the first player it also not good to be the second player if more than 2 players are involved. Clearly, transitive.

Jun-19-17  john barleycorn: <johnlspouge: ...

Define "better"?>

My paraphrasing for <al wazir>'s <X always beats Y>

Jun-19-17  nok: I think Sneaky wants the best play against a random opponent.
Jun-20-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  johnlspouge: <Sneaky>'s problem is a zero-sum two-person game. Its symmetry guarantees a value of 0.0, i.e., best play yields both players no payoff on average. The game's only distinguishing feature seems to be the symmetry of the $20 jars. In principle, the symmetry simplifies the solution. (Section 3.5 in

[ https://www.math.ucla.edu/~tom/Game... ]

describes the simplification: basically you play any symmetries with probabilities equal to each other, and then you average the payoffs of the four symmetric options for the two players to reduce the size of the payoff matrix.) The reduction made no practical difference: I just threw the whole payoff matrix into the online game solver at

[ http://levine.sscnet.ucla.edu/games... ]

The solver uses a simplex method for solving the linear constraints in the minimax criterion for an optimal strategy.

Without simplifying with symmetry, for N marbles and K jars, elementary combinatorics shows that each player has N+K-1 choose K-1 possible plays, so for N=10 and K=3, each player has 12.11/2=66 possible moves; for N=3 and K=3, 5.4/2=10.

The complete payoff matrix for 3 marbles is

(0,0,3) 0,5,5,5,5,-15,-15,5,-15,5
(0,1,2) -5,0,5,5,0,5,-15,25,5,25
(0,2,1) -5,-5,0,5,-25,0,5,0,25,25
(0,3,0) -5,-5,-5,0,-25,-25,0,-25,0,0
(1,0,2) -5,0,25,25,0,5,5,5,-15,5
(1,1,1) 15,-5,0,25,-5,0,5,0,5,25
(1,2,0) 15,15,-5,0,-5,-5,0,-25,0,0
(2,0,1) -5,-25,0,25,-5,0,25,0,5,5
(2,1,0) 15,-5,-25,0,15,-5,0,-5,0,0
(3,0,0) -5,-25,-25,0,-5,-25,0,-5,0,0

where Player 2 (columns) has the same moves as Player 1 (rows). You can check payoffs to see that my program calculates the payoff matrix correctly. The format permits entry into the online calculator with minimal editing. The calculator returns an optimal strategy

(0,0,3) 0
(0,1,2) 0.166666667
(0,2,1) 0
(0,3,0) 0
(1,0,2) 0.166666667
(1,1,1) 0.333333333
(1,2,0) 0.166666667
(2,0,1) 0
(2,1,0) 0.166666667
(3,0,0) 0

which is indeed symmetric in the two $20 jars.

For 10 marbles, it returns an optimal strategy (omitting 0.0 probabilities)

(0,3,7) 0.115384615
(0,5,5) 0.019230769
(1,1,8) 0.057692308
(1,4,5) 0.076923077
(1,6,3) 0.019230769
(2,0,8) 0.019230769
(2,3,5) 0.038461538
(2,6,2) 0.076923077
(3,0,7) 0.038461538
(3,1,6) 0.076923077
(3,6,1) 0.038461538
(4,1,5) 0.019230769
(4,5,1) 0.115384615
(5,2,3) 0.134615385
(5,5,0) 0.019230769
(6,0,4) 0.076923077
(6,4,0) 0.057692308

Note that I edited obvious rounding errors in near-0 probabilities out. The probabilities sum to 1.0, but the given optimal strategy is not symmetric (e.g., (4,6,0) had 0.0 probability, whereas (6,4,0) had probability 0.057692308).

Jun-21-17  john barleycorn: <johnlspouge> setting up the 66 x 66 matrix for gives me slightly different results. (provided I did it right)

For example (4,6,0) and (6,4,0) have the same negative expectation of -3,25 $/game.

My complete list of combinations with positive expectatio:

(0,2,8)

(0,3,7)

(0,4,6)
(0,6,4)
(0,5,5)

(2,0,8)

(3,0,7)

(4,0,6)
(6,0,4)
(5,0,5)

(1,1,8)

(1,2,7)

(2,1,7)

(1,3,6)
(1,6,3)
(3,1,6)
(3,6,1)
(6,1,3)
(6,3,1)
(1,4,5)
(1,5,4)
(4,1,5)
(4,5,1)
(5,1,4)
(5,4,1)
(2,2,6)
(2,6,2)
(6,2,2)
(2,3,5)
(2,5,3)
(3,2,5)
(3,5,2)
(5,2,3)
(5,3,2)
(2,4,4)
(4,2,4)
(4,4,2)
(3,3,4)
(3,4,3)
(4,3,3)

Jun-21-17  john barleycorn: The short version of it:

any permutation of one of the following distributions has a positive expectation: (1,3,6), (1,4,5), (2,2,6), (2,3,5), (2,4,4), (3,3,4)

and any of the following distributions with the first 2 components switched (0,2,8), (0.3,7), (0,4,6), (0,5,5), (0,6,4), (1,1,8), (1,2,7)

It is clear that a distribution (k,l,m) has the same expectation as (l,k,m) (the first 2 components give the marbles in the $20 jars)

Jun-23-17  john barleycorn: <johnlspouge> just look at your 3 marble example.

< ...

The complete payoff matrix for 3 marbles is

...
(1,2,0) 15,15,-5,0,-5,-5,0,-25,0,0
...
(2,1,0) 15,-5,-25,0,15,-5,0,-5,0,0
...>

Well, (1,2,0) and (2,1,0) have -10 payout.

<... The calculator returns an optimal strategy

...
(1,2,0) 0.166666667
...
(2,1,0) 0.166666667 >

Which is very much doubted.

Jun-24-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  johnlspouge: @<john barleycorn>: Theorem 3.1 in the previous web reference

[ https://www.math.ucla.edu/~tom/Game... ]

gives necessary conditions on an optimal solution. A more thorough treament, e.g., Theorem 2.9 in

JCC McKinsey (1952)
Introduction to the Theory of Games
McGraw-Hill

expands the theorem into necessary and sufficient conditions. I checked the necessary and sufficient conditions by hand for the 3-marble case, and the solution I gave is optimal.

Jun-24-17  john barleycorn: <Johnlspouge> with all due respect no strategy reverses a negative payout. I think (1,2,0) and (2,1,0) got mixed up with (0,2,1) and (2,0,1). Also as mentioned (6,4,0) and (4,6,0) must have the same expectation. (on the side why do you always mention probabilities? games are evaluated by their expectation)

(5,5,0) in the 10 marbles variant is also not winning.

These things can be calculated in the "pedestrians" approach.

Jun-26-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  johnlspouge: Player 1 optimally plays the indicated strategy that I gave before, randomizing his plays according to the probabilities I gave before from the online calculator

(0,0,3) 0
(0,1,2) 1/6
(0,2,1) 0
(0,3,0) 0
(1,0,2) 1/6
(1,1,1) 1/3
(1,2,0) 1/6
(2,0,1) 0
(2,1,0) 1/6
(3,0,0) 0

Using the payout matrix (to Player 1) that I gave before, Player 2's pure strategies (indexed below in column form, as Player 1's were, above) yield the indicated expected payouts to Player 1, if Player 1 uses the optimal strategy above. (Multiply the payout by optimal probability and sum over the column of the pure strategy for Player 2 in the payout matrix.)

(0,0,3) 50/6
(0,1,2) 0
(0,2,1) 0
(0,3,0) 80/6
(1,0,2) 0
(1,1,1) 0
(1,2,0) 0
(2,0,1) 0
(2,1,0) 0
(3,0,0) 80/6

Thus, every convex combination of pure strategies for Player 2 forces a non-negative payout from Player 2, so Player 2 can at most hold Player 1 to a 0 payout, which (because the game is symmetric) is the value of the game. Player 2 has the same optimal strategy as Player 1, and (with payout signs reversed) Player 1 can not extract a positive expectation from Player 2.

< <john barleycorn> wrote : on the side why do you always mention probabilities? games are evaluated by their expectation >

The probabilities are the basis of mixed strategies. The references I gave explain them. The online calculator you used provides probabilities for the optimal mixed strategy, and you should have provided them as part of the solution for the optimal strategy.

Jun-26-17  nok: I think the question was best play(s) against a uniformly random opponent, not optimized. (And how it depends on the jar contents' ratio, I guess.)

<I imagine a computer program that selects the distribution entirely at random.>

Jun-26-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  johnlspouge: @<nok> The original intent was not clear. I had assumed that <Sneaky>'s mention of a uniform strategy was musing, because otherwise the problem is a trivial calculation. <al wazir> seems to interpret the problem as I did.
Jun-26-17
Premium Chessgames Member
  johnlspouge: @<john barleycorn>: Apologies about the online calculator, which is irrelevant to the problem you were solving.
Jump to page #    (enter # from 1 to 291)
search thread:   
< Earlier Kibitzing  · PAGE 291 OF 291 ·  Later Kibitzing>
NOTE: You need to pick a username and password to post a reply. Getting your account takes less than a minute, totally anonymous, and 100% free--plus, it entitles you to features otherwise unavailable. Pick your username now and join the chessgames community!
If you already have an account, you should login now.
Please observe our posting guidelines:
  1. No obscene, racist, sexist, or profane language.
  2. No spamming, advertising, or duplicating posts.
  3. No personal attacks against other members.
  4. Nothing in violation of United States law.
  5. No posting personal information of members.
Blow the Whistle See something that violates our rules? Blow the whistle and inform an administrator.


NOTE: Keep all discussion on the topic of this page. This forum is for this specific player and nothing else. If you want to discuss chess in general, or this site, you might try the Kibitzer's Café.
Messages posted by Chessgames members do not necessarily represent the views of Chessgames.com, its employees, or sponsors.
Spot an error? Please suggest your correction and help us eliminate database mistakes!


home | about | login | logout | F.A.Q. | your profile | preferences | Premium Membership | Kibitzer's Café | Biographer's Bistro | new kibitzing | chessforums | Tournament Index | Player Directory | World Chess Championships | Opening Explorer | Guess the Move | Game Collections | ChessBookie Game | Chessgames Challenge | Store | privacy notice | advertising | contact us
Copyright 2001-2017, Chessgames Services LLC